ラベル finance の投稿を表示しています。 すべての投稿を表示
ラベル finance の投稿を表示しています。 すべての投稿を表示

2009年4月20日月曜日

Weight P/E by P*E ?

A while ago, Jeremy Siegel attacked P/E ratio calculated by S&P for overestimating the real value (here and here. HT Greg mankiw's Blog).

S&P are now using the following formula:


where Vi is the market value and Ei is the earning of issue i, and PER denotes P/E ratio.
Siegel asserts that S&P should weight both market value(numerator) and earning(divisor) by market value, such as:



Siegel says that this weighting will alleviate the problem of overestimating the overall P/E ratio, because the huge loss of the company like AIG will be downplayed by its relatively small market value, in comparison with S&P formula .


However, when you transform S&P formula as follows, you can see that it is also a kind of weighted sum:



That is, individual P/E ratio is weighted by earning.


When you look at Seigel's formula, it can be re-written as follows:



That is, individual P/E ratio is weighted by the product of value and earning.

It can also transformed as follows:


Individual P/E ratio is weighted by the product of P/E and squared earning.

From these transformations, you can see that the meaning of Siegel's formula is much harder to grasp than S&P one.


For Siegel's purpose, maybe it's better to weight individual earning by market value, instead of by earning in S&P formula, as follows:




 

2009年4月11日土曜日

The Geithner put : general PDF case

In the previous two posts, I showed general formula of break-even purchase price and fund's gain/loss under the Geithner plan. I also did some arithmetic using two-state model.

Krugman wrote "the natural way to think about these things is in fact in terms of simple two-state numerical examples." Nemo commented "binomial distribution is oversimplified."

However, two-state model may be not so simple as it seems. It can be described as reduced form of more general case.

Let p(P) the probability density function(PDF) of P. Then P1, P2, p1 in the two-state model I used can be derived from p(P) as follows:



where Pb is break-even purchase price, and (1-k) is ratio of non-recourse loan offered by FDIC.

As derived here, Pb is function of P1 and p1. That is, Pb = p1P1 / (p1+k(1-p1)). So Pb and P1, p1 must be calculated simultaneously.

As for general PDF, that calculation can be done by Excel. Below I show how to do the calculation by Excel for three forms of p(P), i.e. uniform distribution, normal distribution, log-normal distribution.

  • uniform distribution

p1P1Pb
Excel row/columnABC
2Initial valueInitial value=A2*B2/(A2+$G$2*(1-A2))
3=($I$2-C2*(1-$G$2))/($I$2-$H$2)=($I$2^2-(C2*(1-$G$2))^2)/2/($I$2-$H$2)/A3=A3*B3/(A3+$G$2*(1-A3))



Input k in G2 cell, and upper limit of uniform distribution in I2 cell, lower limit in H2 cell.
If you drag fill handle of 3rd row to appropriate row (say, 41st row), then each value of Pb, P1, p1 will converge.



  • normal distribution


p1P1Pb
Excel row/columnABC
2Initial valueInitial value=A2*B2/(A2+$G$2*(1-A2))
3=1-NORMDIST(C2*(1-$G$2),$H$2,$I$2,TRUE)=(EXP(-((((1-$G$2)*C2-$H$2)/$I$2))^2/2)*$I$2/SQRT(2*PI())+$H$2*A3)/A3=A3*B3/(A3+$G$2*(1-A3))



Input k in G2 cell, and mean of normal distribution in H2 cell, standard deviation in I2 cell.
If you drag fill handle of 3rd row to appropriate row (say, 41st row), then each value of Pb, P1, p1 will converge (if they ever do).

(Note: Above Excel formula is based on normal distribution without restriction, so price could be negative.)




  • log-normal distribution


p1P1Pb
Excel row/columnABC
2Initial valueInitial value=A2*B2/(A2+$G$2*(1-A2))
3=1-LOGNORMDIST(C2*(1-$G$2),$H$2,$I$2)=(1-NORMDIST( (LN(C2*(1-$G$2))-$H$2)/$I$2,$I$2,1,TRUE))*EXP($I$2^2/2+$H$2)/A3=A3*B3/(A3+$G$2*(1-A3))



Input k in G2 cell, and mean of log-normal distribution in H2 cell, standard deviation in I2 cell.
If you drag fill handle of 3rd row to appropriate row (say, 41st row), then each value of Pb, P1, p1 will converge (if they ever do).



 

The Geithner put : option formula

In the previous post , I showed the general formula of break-even purchase price under Geithner plan.

In that post, I showed the gain/loss of the investment fund as follows:
   w(P - Pb)   if P >= (1-k)Pb
   -wPb      if P < (1-k)Pb
where:
P is true price of the loan,
Pb is the purchase price,
(1-k) is ratio of non-recourse loan offered by FDIC (6/7 in case of Geithner plan),
w is ratio of fund money in investment (1/2 in case of Geithner plan; the rest(=1-w) is funded by Treasury).

It also can expressed in option formula as follows:
   w{Max(P-Pb , -kPb)}
  =w{Max(P-(1-k)Pb , 0)-kPb}

This is the formula of call option with strike price=-(1-k)Pb and option purchase price=kPb (See image below).


By applying the above option formula, it can be calculates as
   0.5*{(0.5*(100-84*6/7)+0.5*0)-84/7}=1
which corresponds to Nemos's result.

As Nemo showed, the money fund put in is wkPb=0.5*1/7*84=6. So the fund performance reaches 1/6*100=16.67%.

FDIC gain/loss also can be expressed in option formula as follows:
   -Max(0 , (1-k)Pb-P)
(In fact, maximum gain is not zero, as there is interest revenue. Here I ignore it for simplicity)

This is the formula of put option with strike price=-(1-k)Pb (See image below).


The FDIC position is short on this put option, and that "Geithner put" is what enables the floor part of the fund's call option shown above.


 

2009年4月10日金曜日

The Geithner put : general formula

Many people have been calculating the effect of Geithner put in the Geithner plan (aka PPIP) . However, while many have shown numerical examples, seldom of them have shown the general formula. So I am going to give one.

Usually, when a fund purchases loan from bank, its gain/loss can be written as
   P - Pb
where P is true price of the loan, and Pb is the purchase price.
Therefore, expected return of the fund becomes zero when Pb=E[P]
(E[.] denotes expectation value).

But with Geithner put, the gain/loss of the fund becomes
   w(P - Pb)   if P >= (1-k)Pb
   -wPb      if P < (1-k)Pb
where:
(1-k) is ratio of non-recourse loan offered by FDIC (6/7 in case of Geithner plan),
w is ratio of fund money in investment (1/2 in case of Geithner plan; the rest(=1-w) is funded by Treasury).

In this case, Pb, the break-even purchase price, is not necessarily E[P].

Now let P becomes P1 with probability p1, and P2 with probability 1-p1.
(Assumption: P1 >= (1-k)Pb > P2)

Then the break-even purchase price can be written as
   Pb = p1P1 / (p1+k(1-p1))

RHS does not include P2, which means one does not have to consider P2 as for down-side risk. This is because if down-side event really happens, the price P2 does not affect the loss of the fund; the fund just loses the money it put in.

Let confirm this formula by Krugman's example. In Krugman's case, p1=0.5, P1=150, k=0.15, so Pb becomes 130.43, which corresponds to Krugman's calculation.

Jeffrey Sachs also showed numerical example. His setting is p1=0.2, P1=1,000,000, k=0.1. Then Pb becomes 714,268, which corresponds to Sachs's calculation.

And in this case, break-even price Pb is always higher than expectation value of P. That result can be shown by the following arithmetic:

 Pb-E[P]
=p1P1 / (p1+k(1-p1)) - (p1P1+(1-p1)P2)
=p1P1 [1/{p1+k(1-p1)} -1] - (1-p1)P2
=p1P1[(1-k)(1-p1)/{p1+k(1-p1)}] - (1-p1)P2
=(1-p1)[p1P1(1-k)/{p1+k(1-p1)} - P2]
=(1-p1)[(1-k)Pb-P2]

This value is always positive by assumption. And this value represents the "subsidy" to the bank under the Geithner plan.

And if the purchase price is higher than break-even price Pb by, say, R, it adds to that subsidy to the bank.
In that case, the private invester loss is -wR(p1+(1-p1)k), Treasury loss is -(1-w)R(p1+(1-p1)k).
And FDIC loss becomes larger by -R(1-(p1+(1-p1)k)).
Graph below shows the loss of the three stake holders as function of p1 (total=100%; k=1/7, a=1/2 as in the Geithner plan).
 

Loss of FDIC+Treasury makes up 80% of total when p1=0.3, and becomes less than 70% only when p1 is larger than 0.6.


 

フォロワー

自己紹介

This blog is some thoughts on economics by a Japanese non-economist. Translated from my Japanese blog.